This paper is based on a growth model that is consistent with salient features of the recent “New Normal” growth experience in China: slowdown of growth rate, low level of inflation and unemployment, decreasing returns on capital investment, extensive reallocation among agriculture, manufacturing and modern service sectors, rising share of consumption, improvement of wealth distribution, and reduced foreign surplus. The building blocks of the theory are asymmetric technology diffusions from FDI firms among various sectors and nominal wage rigidity in the labor market. Due to the asymmetric technology diffusion among different sectors, manufacturing firms enjoy a more rapid productivity progress via the process of learning by doing in a processing on order economy. Thus manufacturing sectors serve as the engine in the past years’ economic growth in China. Through the competition in labor market, trends of wage equalization drive the migration of residents from agriculture to manufacturing and modern service sectors. Moreover, with a larger share of processing on order firms, China tends to further enlarge her foreign surplus in a faster pace. However, the result of this paper shows that since the exchange rate reform on July 21st 2005, RMB has appreciated accumulatively by 35%, combined with the wage rigidity in labor market, FDI firms in manufacturing sectors face an increasing level of cost in terms of increasing wage expenditure. Incumbent low profitable firms exit and potential entrants with new technology no more settle down. Thus, rapid productivity progress ceases in manufacturing sector. Not only the growth rate slows down, but also large number of unemployed population reallocates back to modern service and agriculture sectors. Dwindling share of manufacturing sectors reduced the foreign surplus by the drops of processing on order infra-firm trade of FDI firms.
Published in | Economics (Volume 5, Issue 3) |
DOI | 10.11648/j.eco.20160503.11 |
Page(s) | 27-45 |
Creative Commons |
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, provided the original work is properly cited. |
Copyright |
Copyright © The Author(s), 2016. Published by Science Publishing Group |
Asymmetric Technology Diffusion, Nominal Wage Rigidity, Reallocation Among Sectors, “New Normal” in China
[1] | Arrow K J. The economic implications of learning by doing [M]. Palgrave Macmillan UK, 1971. |
[2] | Bewley T F. Why wages don't fall during a recession [M]. Harvard University Press, 1999. |
[3] | Burgess R, Venables A. Towards a microeconomics of growth [M]. World Bank Publications, 2004. |
[4] | Coe D T, Helpman E, Hoffmaister A W. North-South R&D Spillovers [J]. Cepr Discussion Papers, 1995, volume 107 (107): 134-149 (16). |
[5] | Coe D T, Moghadam R. Capital and trade as engines of growth in France: An application of Johansen's cointegration methodology [J]. Staff Papers-International Monetary Fund, 1993: 542-566. |
[6] | Davies G. 2014, Watch China’s exchange rate policy, The Financial Times http://blogs.ft.com/gavyndavies/2014/02/25/watch-chinas-exchange-rate-policy/ |
[7] | Dickens W T, Goette L, Groshen E L, et al. How wages change: micro evidence from the International Wage Flexibility Project [J]. National Bank of Belgium Working Paper, 2006 (96). |
[8] | Dietmar Harhoff. R&D and Productivity in German Manufacturing Firms [J]. Economics of Innovation & New Technology, 1998, 6 (1): 29-50. |
[9] | Easterly W, Levine R. It's not factor accumulation: stylized facts and growth models [J]. 2002. |
[10] | Eaton J, Kortum S. International patenting and technology diffusion [R]. National Bureau of Economic Research, 1994. |
[11] | Hall R E, Jones C I. Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? [R]. National bureau of economic research, 1999. |
[12] | Henderson J V. Chapter 24 – Urbanization and Growth [J]. Handbook of Economic Growth, 2005, 1 (05): 1543-1591. |
[13] | Howitt P, Aghion P. Capital accumulation and innovation as complementary factors in long-run growth [J]. Journal of Economic Growth, 1998, 3 (2): 111-130. |
[14] | Keller W. International technology diffusion. J Econ Lit [J]. Journal of Economic Literature, 2002, 42 (3). |
[15] | Klenow P, Rodriguez-Clare A. The neoclassical revival in growth economics: Has it gone too far? [M]//NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1997, Volume 12. MIT Press, 1997: 73-114. |
[16] | Knoppik C, Beissinger T. Downward nominal wage rigidity in Europe: an analysis of European micro data from the ECHP 1994–2001[J]. Empirical Economics, 2009, 36 (2): 321-338. |
[17] | Kraay A. Household saving in China [J]. The World Bank Economic Review, 2000, 14 (3): 545-570. |
[18] | Kuijs L. Investment and Saving in China [J]. Social Science Electronic Publishing, 2005: 1-20. |
[19] | Landes D S. The Unbound Prometheus [J]. General Information, 1969. |
[20] | Lewis W A. Economic development with unlimited supplies of labour [J]. The manchester school, 1954, 22 (2): 139-191. |
[21] | Lucas R E. On the mechanics of economic development [J]. Journal of monetary economics, 1988, 22 (1): 3-42. |
[22] | Lucas R E. Life Earnings and Rural-Urban Migration [J]. Journal of Political Economy, 2004, 112 (S 1): 29-29. |
[23] | Madden G, Savage S J. R & D Spillovers, Information Technology and Telecommunications, and Productivity in Asia and the OECD [J]. Information Economics & Policy, 2000, 12 (4): 367-392. |
[24] | Prescott E C. Lawrence R. Klein Lecture 1997: Needed: A Theory of Total Factor Productivity [J]. International Economic Review, 1998, 39 (3): 525-551. |
[25] | Romer P. Endogenous technological change [R]. National Bureau of Economic Research, 1989. |
[26] | Saggi K. Trade, foreign direct investment, and international technology transfer: A survey [J]. The World Bank Research Observer, 2002, 17 (2): 191-235. |
[27] | Tilford S. Rebalancing the Chinese economy [J]. Centre for European Reform, 2009. |
[28] | Tyers R. China After the Crisis: The Elemental Macroeconomics [J]. Asian Economic Journal, 2002, 15 (2): 173-198. |
[29] | Williamson J G. Migration and urbanization in the Third World [J]. 1986. |
[30] | Yang J, Zhang W, Tokgoz S. Macroeconomic impacts of Chinese currency appreciation on China and the Rest of World: A global CGE analysis [J]. Journal of Policy Modeling, 2013, 35 (6): 1029-1042. |
[31] | Yang X, Borland J. A microeconomic mechanism for economic growth [J]. Journal of political economy, 1991: 460-482. |
[32] | Yang, Yao. (2013), “A New Normal, but with Robust Growth: China’s Growth Prospects in the Next 10 Years”, THINK TANK 20: Growth, Convergence and Income Distribution: The Road from the Brisbane G-20 Summit. |
[33] | Zyurt S, Main F A. Currency Undervaluation and Economic Rebalancing towards Services: Is China an Exception? [J]. China & World Economy, 2013, 21 (1): 47-63. |
APA Style
Ge Song. (2016). Asymmetric Technology Diffusion, Nominal Wage Rigidity, and the “New Normal” in China. Economics, 5(3), 27-45. https://doi.org/10.11648/j.eco.20160503.11
ACS Style
Ge Song. Asymmetric Technology Diffusion, Nominal Wage Rigidity, and the “New Normal” in China. Economics. 2016, 5(3), 27-45. doi: 10.11648/j.eco.20160503.11
AMA Style
Ge Song. Asymmetric Technology Diffusion, Nominal Wage Rigidity, and the “New Normal” in China. Economics. 2016;5(3):27-45. doi: 10.11648/j.eco.20160503.11
@article{10.11648/j.eco.20160503.11, author = {Ge Song}, title = {Asymmetric Technology Diffusion, Nominal Wage Rigidity, and the “New Normal” in China}, journal = {Economics}, volume = {5}, number = {3}, pages = {27-45}, doi = {10.11648/j.eco.20160503.11}, url = {https://doi.org/10.11648/j.eco.20160503.11}, eprint = {https://article.sciencepublishinggroup.com/pdf/10.11648.j.eco.20160503.11}, abstract = {This paper is based on a growth model that is consistent with salient features of the recent “New Normal” growth experience in China: slowdown of growth rate, low level of inflation and unemployment, decreasing returns on capital investment, extensive reallocation among agriculture, manufacturing and modern service sectors, rising share of consumption, improvement of wealth distribution, and reduced foreign surplus. The building blocks of the theory are asymmetric technology diffusions from FDI firms among various sectors and nominal wage rigidity in the labor market. Due to the asymmetric technology diffusion among different sectors, manufacturing firms enjoy a more rapid productivity progress via the process of learning by doing in a processing on order economy. Thus manufacturing sectors serve as the engine in the past years’ economic growth in China. Through the competition in labor market, trends of wage equalization drive the migration of residents from agriculture to manufacturing and modern service sectors. Moreover, with a larger share of processing on order firms, China tends to further enlarge her foreign surplus in a faster pace. However, the result of this paper shows that since the exchange rate reform on July 21st 2005, RMB has appreciated accumulatively by 35%, combined with the wage rigidity in labor market, FDI firms in manufacturing sectors face an increasing level of cost in terms of increasing wage expenditure. Incumbent low profitable firms exit and potential entrants with new technology no more settle down. Thus, rapid productivity progress ceases in manufacturing sector. Not only the growth rate slows down, but also large number of unemployed population reallocates back to modern service and agriculture sectors. Dwindling share of manufacturing sectors reduced the foreign surplus by the drops of processing on order infra-firm trade of FDI firms.}, year = {2016} }
TY - JOUR T1 - Asymmetric Technology Diffusion, Nominal Wage Rigidity, and the “New Normal” in China AU - Ge Song Y1 - 2016/06/23 PY - 2016 N1 - https://doi.org/10.11648/j.eco.20160503.11 DO - 10.11648/j.eco.20160503.11 T2 - Economics JF - Economics JO - Economics SP - 27 EP - 45 PB - Science Publishing Group SN - 2376-6603 UR - https://doi.org/10.11648/j.eco.20160503.11 AB - This paper is based on a growth model that is consistent with salient features of the recent “New Normal” growth experience in China: slowdown of growth rate, low level of inflation and unemployment, decreasing returns on capital investment, extensive reallocation among agriculture, manufacturing and modern service sectors, rising share of consumption, improvement of wealth distribution, and reduced foreign surplus. The building blocks of the theory are asymmetric technology diffusions from FDI firms among various sectors and nominal wage rigidity in the labor market. Due to the asymmetric technology diffusion among different sectors, manufacturing firms enjoy a more rapid productivity progress via the process of learning by doing in a processing on order economy. Thus manufacturing sectors serve as the engine in the past years’ economic growth in China. Through the competition in labor market, trends of wage equalization drive the migration of residents from agriculture to manufacturing and modern service sectors. Moreover, with a larger share of processing on order firms, China tends to further enlarge her foreign surplus in a faster pace. However, the result of this paper shows that since the exchange rate reform on July 21st 2005, RMB has appreciated accumulatively by 35%, combined with the wage rigidity in labor market, FDI firms in manufacturing sectors face an increasing level of cost in terms of increasing wage expenditure. Incumbent low profitable firms exit and potential entrants with new technology no more settle down. Thus, rapid productivity progress ceases in manufacturing sector. Not only the growth rate slows down, but also large number of unemployed population reallocates back to modern service and agriculture sectors. Dwindling share of manufacturing sectors reduced the foreign surplus by the drops of processing on order infra-firm trade of FDI firms. VL - 5 IS - 3 ER -